Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. Both passages acknowledge the effectiveness of U.S. farm subsidies in
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. The first sentence of Passage 1 refers primarily to the author’s belief that
1 Crore+ students have signed up on EduRev. Have you? Download the App |
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. The author of Passage 2 would most likely regard the “taxes” mentioned in line 15 as
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. The author of Passage 1 believes that the GAO report “probably won’t” (line 9) horrify lawmakers because
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. Which of the following provides the strongest evidence for the answer to the previous question?
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. Unlike Passage 1, Passage 2 emphasizes the danger of
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. Passage 1 mentions the results of the 2009 poll (lines 42–45) primarily to
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. If the author of Passage 1 were to use the data in the graph to support his main thesis, he would most likely mention
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. If the author of Passage 2 were to use the data in the graph to support his main thesis, he would most likely mention
Question are based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. The author of Passage 1 would most likely say that the “benefit” in line 87 is
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. Unlike Passage 2, Passage 1 makes a direct appeal to the reader’s
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
Passage 1 is adapted from Nicholas Heidorn, “The Enduring Political Illusion of Farm Subsidies.” ©2004 The Independent Institute. Originally Published August 18, 2004 in the San Francisco Chronicle. Passage 2 is ©2015 by Mark Anestis. Since 1922, the U.S. government has subsidized the agricultural industry by supporting the price of crops (commodity subsidies), paying farmers let their fields go fallow (conservation subsidies), helping farmers purchase crop insurance (crop insurance subsidies), and compensating farmers for uninsured losses due to disasters (disaster subsidies). The following passages discuss these programs.
Passage 1
Something is rotten down on the farm. A recent
General Accounting Office study found that the
U.S. farm subsidy program, a multibillion-dollar
system of direct payments to American farmers,
(5) uses administrators who are ill-trained and
poorly monitored, and who give away millions
of taxpayer dollars to farmers who are actually
ineligible for the program. This report should
horrify lawmakers, but it probably won’t.
(10) From 1995 to 2002, the United States Congress
doled out more than $114 billion to farmers. Why?
One misconception is that subsidies are
a boon to consumers because they lower food
prices. This ignores the fact that consumers are
(15) also paying for these subsidies through taxes.
Because of inefficiencies in the program, we
taxpayers will pay more in taxes than we will ever
get back in lower corn or wheat prices.
In fact, farm subsidies are not even intended
(20) to reduce food prices significantly. When prices
are too low, farmers lose money. To prevent this
situation, Congress also pays farmers additional
“conservation subsidies” to leave their land fallow,
thereby lowering supply and boosting prices again.
(25) We’re taxed to lower prices, and then taxed to raise them again.
Another myth is that subsidies increase
exports, and thereby benefit the American
economy, by lowering the price of farm products
(30) and so making them more attractive to foreign
consumers. This ignores two realities. First,
farm subsidies transfer wealth from taxpayers
to foreign consumers just as efficiently as
they transfer wealth to domestic consumers.
(35) Second, farm subsidies are actually harming
American exporters. In March 2005, the World
Trade Organization ruled that American cotton
subsidies violated global free-trade rules, which
could lead to billions of dollars in retaliatory
(40) tariffs or penalties.
The worst misconception is that we need these
subsidies to save the small family farmer. Indeed,
according to a 2009 poll, about 77 percent of
Americans support giving subsidies to small family
(45) farms. But according to the Environmental Working
Group, 71 percent of farm subsidies go to the top
10 percent of beneficiaries, almost all of which are
large corporate farms. By subsidizing these rich
farmers, we actually make it much harder for the
(50) small family farmers to compete, not to mention
the millions of impoverished third world farmers
who rely on farming for their livelihood.
Rich corporate farmers are an enormously
powerful lobby in American politics. Agribusines
(55) and farm insurance lobbies pump nearly $100
million into political campaigns every year, and
the floodgates show no sign of closing. So don’t be
surprised if the GAO’s reports of mismanagement
and waste go unheeded. Politicians like their
(60) payouts almost as much as the big farmers and
their insurance companies do.
Passage 2
The critics of the U.S. farm subsidy program fail
to recognize just how vital these subsidies really
are. They are not as burdensome to American
(65) taxpayers as the critics claim, and indeed provide
important benefits. By protecting farmers from
damaging fluctuations in commodity prices due
to weather disasters or market disruptions, these
subsidies help sustain a vital American industry.
(70) At the same time, they protect consumers from
price spikes that can accompany steep drops in
crop inventories. Before price supports became
common in the 20th century, crop failures
devastated the lives of farmers and consumers with
(75) horrifying frequency.
Opponents say that subsidies distort the
free market and create surpluses in supply. But
halting subsidies would allow regular shortfalls,
which are far more damaging. The year-to-year
(80) carryover of these surpluses protects farmers
from low prices and consumers from high prices.
Another misconception is that subsidies
only benefit the producers. In fact, they help
many related industries as well, including food
(85) processing, distribution, and marketing, chiefly
by helping to lower the cost of production. And,
of course, the consumers receive the benefit of
lower prices.
When assessing the costs and benefits of
(90) farm payments, it is important to compare these
subsidies to those of other industrialized nations.
American farmers receive an average of just 20% of
their incomes from subsidies, compared to 70% for
farmers from some other countries. The European
(95) Union spends about five times what the United
States spends on farm subsidies, amounting to
45% of the EU budget, compared to less than 1%
of the U.S. federal budget. Although the U.S. farm
subsidies programs are not perfect, they provide
(100) enormous benefits not only to farms but also
to associated industries employing millions of
people and to nearly every American consumer.
Q. In line 57, the “floodgates” are controls against
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. The narrator characterizes Reverend Jansen primarily as
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. The narrator’s statement that her mother “had been murdered” (line 2) is best taken to mean that
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. The narrator’s description of the reverend’s “eyes” and “breath” in lines 15–16 primarily convey a sense of
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. Christine believes that Sarah’s ethnicity is
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. Which choice provides the best evidence for the answer to the previous question?
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. Lines 27–29 (“God kills . . . my mother”) are striking for their use of
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. Lines 36–44 chiefly describe Christine’s
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. In line 45, “charged” most nearly means
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. The passage suggests that Uncle Henry’s role in the Thorson family is that of
Question based on the following passage.
This passage is adapted from Marie Myung-Ok Lee, Somebody’s Daughter. ©2006 Beacon Press. The story is about a Korean-American girl adopted by an American family and raised in the Midwest.
When I was eight, they told me that my mother’s
death was preordained. She had been murdered.
One Sunday after service, our minister,
Reverend Jansen of the Lutheran Church of the
(5) Good Shepherd, bent down in a cloud of Aqua
Velva to explain. We had been learning in Sunday
school about Heaven and Hell, and in the middle
of class I had fallen into a panic, wondering how
I would recognize my Korean mother when I saw
(10) her in Heaven—or in Hell, if perhaps she and I
both sinned too much.
Not to worry, I was told.
“God called your Korean parents home so
that you could become the daughter of your
(15) mother and father,” he said, his eyes sliding
sidewise, for just a second. His breath smelled
vaguely of toast.
“It was all part of His plan—you see how much
your mommy and daddy love you? When the time
(20) comes, if you’re a very good girl, you, your mommy,
daddy, and your sister, Amanda—the whole
Thorson family—will be in heaven together, thanks
to the Lord’s wonderful and mysterious ways.”
“That’s why we named you Sarah,” Christine
(25) and Ken added. “Because it means ‘God’s
precious treasure.’”
God kills, I thought then. The same God who
brought us Christmas and the Easter Bunny—he
murdered my mother.
(30) Shortly after that Sunday, I brought up
my Korean mother again, asking about the car
accident, how it happened, exactly—was it like
Phil Haag’s father, who fell asleep at the wheel? Or
like our plumber’s teenage son who drove into a
(35) semi head-on?
“Sarah,” Christine said patiently, looking
up from the chopping board, where she was
slicing carrot discs for pot roast. “We really knew
nothing about her. I’m your mommy. Let’s not
(40) talk about this any more, it makes me sad.” She
made little crying motions, pretending to wipe
away tears, the same thing she did when I was
bad, to show how I had disappointed her.
I grew up in a house in which Korea had
(45) always been the oddly charged word, never to be
mentioned in connection to me, the same way
we never said “Uncle Henry” and “alcoholic” in
the same sentence. It was almost as if Ken and
Christine thought I needed to be protected from
(50) it, the way small children need to be protected
from boors itching to tell them that Santa Claus
is not real.The ban on Korea extended even to
the aforementioned Uncle Henry, who was then
deprived of his war stories at our Memorial Day
(55) cookouts. Although he proudly wore his felt VFW
hat with its flurry of pins, including ones from his
tour “overseas,” Christine or Ken would quietly
slip him some of his favorite Pabst or Schlitz, and
in return he’d set up residence in the lawn chair
(60) at the far corner of our yard, away from everyone.
Somewhere back in the fuzzy clot of my
teens (now, I’m at the worldly-wise age of almost-
twenty), the ’88 Summer Olympics were held
in Seoul. We couldn’t buck the Thorson family
(65) tradition of watching absolutely everything (that
winter we’d raptly watched curling, for God’s
sakes!). But I was aware that pains were taken
to modulate voices, vocal cords twisted to an
excruciating, studied casualness until Korea
(70) came out “Korea,” exactly the same way we’d say
“Russia” or “Carl Lewis” or “Flo-Jo.”
Then Bryant Gumbel invaded our living room
with his special segment on how Korea, one of the
four “Little Tiger” economic miracle countries,
(75) was so enterprising that it had even made an
export product out of its babies. Since the Korean
War, more than a hundred thousand children,
Made-in-Korea stamped on their foreheads, had
left the country, their adoption fees fattening the
(80) government coffers.
Top that, Singapore! Gumbel’s cheery smirk
seemed to say.
“Well, Sarah’s really American, not Kor—”
Amanda began, until the look on Christine’s
(85) face—despairing, fierce—stopped her.
We invent what becomes us.
Q. The “cheery smirk” (line 81) is taken by the narrator to indicate Gumbel’s
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. This passage is primarily concerned with
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. In the context of the passage as a whole, the Gettysburg Cyclorama represents
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. Lines 11–13 (“Unfortunately . . . human eyes”) convey the author’s disappointment in
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. The quotation marks around the words “invisible” (line 26) and “see” (line 28) serve primarily to
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. The “moment a swaddled one-day-old opens its eyes” (lines 22–23) corresponds to the instant that
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. In line 64, “distinctive” most nearly means
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. Which of the following can be inferred about the work that earned Penzias and Wilson the Nobel Prize?
Question based on the following passage and supplementary material.
This passage is adapted from G. M. Fitzhenry, “Baby Pictures of the Universe.” ©2015 by College Hill Coaching.
At the breathtaking Gettysburg Cyclorama,
a 377-foot-long, 42-foot-high painting of the bloody
1863 Battle of Gettysburg, visitors can turn in
every direction and feel as if they have been thrust
(5) into the midst of perhaps the most important
battle in American history, a snapshot of a chaotic
chapter in the early life of a nation. Yet right now
you sit in the midst of an even more spectacular
cyclorama of an even more cataclysmic historical
(10) event that took place billions of years ago.
Unfortunately, to appreciate its full splendor, you
would have to be able to see microwaves, which
are invisible to our human eyes.
This real-life cyclorama is the cosmic
(15) microwave background (CMB) radiation, a
13-billion-year-old panoramic snapshot of
the universe as it appeared the moment it first
released its primordial photons. Although it is an
astonishingly detailed confirmation of the Big Bang
(20) theory, it is not actually a picture of the Big Bang.
On a human scale, it corresponds not to the instant
of childbirth, but rather the moment a swaddled
one-day-old opens its eyes and keeps them open.
For the first 380,000 years of its life (a mere
(25) blink of an eye in cosmic history), the universe was
“invisible” because its photons—the particles that
are emitted from an object or event and that must
reach a detector in order for us to “see” it—were
trapped in a hot, opaque fog of hydrogen plasma.
(30) Only when this super-heated plasma cooled to the
point where protons and electrons could combine
to form hydrogen atoms—a period called the
“epoch of recombination”—did these photons
begin to travel unimpeded through the universe.
(35) Some of those photons, having traveled for half a
billion generations, are just now reaching us.
One of the most striking aspects of the CMB
radiation is its near-uniformity, or “isotropism.” No
matter where we look in the sky, the temperature of
(40) the CMB radiation varies by no more than one part in
100,000. It’s almost impossible to find another
real-life example of such thermal homogeneity.
This uniformity is somewhat counterintuitive:
the remnants of most explosions seem to spread
(45) out in a spherical but non-uniform “debris field.”
For instance, the embers of a firework explosion
are confined to a region around the explosion, but
nowhere else. So why is the CMB radiation still
found everywhere in the universe, and not just on
(50) its “edges?” The first reason is that the universe
has no edges: it is “boundless,” just as the surface
of a sphere is boundless. The second reason is that
the CMB radiation did not originate from just one
point in space, but from virtually every point in
(55) space. Thus, every point in the modern universe is
not only equally likely to be the source of the CMB
radiation, it is also equally likely to be the current
location of the CMB radiation.
This uniformity was predicted in a theory
(60) published by George Gamow in 1948. His theory
also made two other predictions that have
been confirmed to astonishing precision by
our current data. First, Gamow predicted that
the CMB radiation should have a distinctive
(65) spectrum known as a “blackbody” curve. Second,
he predicted that the expanding universe would
have cooled this radiation to below 5 degrees
Kelvin today.
(70) The CMB radiation went undetected until
1964, when Arno Penzias and Robert Wilson
at Bell Laboratories in Murray Hill, New Jersey
became troubled by persistent background noise
in a radio telescope that they had just built. Their
initial explanation was that it was due to a “white
(75) dielectric substance,” more commonly known as
pigeon droppings. Remarkably, less than 40 miles
away, Princeton researchers Robert Dicke and
Dave Wilkinson had been searching for evidence
supporting Gamow’s predictions, and instantly
(80) knew of a much better explanation for the noise.
Penzias and Wilson shared the 1978 Nobel Prize in
physics for their discovery of the CMB radiation.
Since then, much more careful observations,
made by the NASA Cosmic Background Explorer
(85) (COBE) and the Wilkinson Microwave Anisotropy
Probe (WMAP) have confirmed that the CMB
radiation indeed has a nearly perfect blackbody
spectrum corresponding to a temperature of
2.725° Kelvin, barely more than 2 degrees from
(90) Gamow’s guess. In addition to confirming many
aspects of the Big Bang theory, these data have
also helped scientists calibrate the age of the
universe (13.772 ± 0.059 billion years), gauge
the speed at which the universe is expanding,
(95) and even verify the existence of “dark energy,”
the mysterious energy that propelled the rapid
expansion of the early universe.
Q. Which choice provides the best evidence for the answer to the previous question?